The world needs an effective IMF. Countries have become hugely indebted following the COVID-19 pandemic, and the risk of new shocks grows as the world warms and new pathogens emerge. Protectionism (sometimes cloaked by security interests) is on the rise, impeding traditional pathways to development. As economies falter, no one wants to absorb the desperate people who are braving dense jungles or climbing onto rickety, overcrowded boats in search of decent livelihoods.
We need an honest broker to help countries negotiate fair rules for international exchange (including, most immediately, rules on subsidies), to call out violators, to criticize bad policies and to step in as lender of last resort for those in distress. Unfortunately, the IMF, despite the high quality of its management and staff, is increasingly ill-positioned to perform these tasks.
The institution’s problems lie in its anachronistic governance. Most key decisions, including on country loans, are made by the Fund’s executive board, where G7 members hold most of the power. The US wields a de facto veto, and Japan’s voting power exceeds that of China, whose economy dwarfs Japan’s. India’s vote share is far smaller than the UK’s or France’s, even though its economy is larger and growing faster than both.
Because the world’s erstwhile dominant powers refuse to let go, the underrepresentation of fast-growing emerging economies persists. At the same time, it is no longer clear that the old powers always have the global interest at heart. In the immediate postwar era, the US, as the sole economic superpower, could be trusted to enforce the rules of the game and generally remain above the fray. However, as its worries about being overtaken have grown, it has switched from referee to player. Once a champion of the idea that openness benefits everyone, it increasingly wants openness only on its own terms.
The quality of the Fund’s lending decisions is also likely to deteriorate. Whenever the Fund lends, it is natural that well-connected countries in economic trouble tend to obtain more relief on easier terms. While there have always been political influences on Fund lending, there has been a greater chance of it succeeding in the past because of outside assistance from powerful board members — think, for example, of the Mexican crisis in 1994, where the US contributed a hefty share of the rescue package.
With fiscal resources now tight even in the G7, the IMF increasingly would have to risk its capital as powerful board members with relatively little skin in the game direct loans toward friends and neighbors. Worse, such special treatment may not even help the loan recipients, many of whom need tough love.
In sum, the IMF’s governance structure would increasingly hurt the Fund’s work. However, would redistributing IMF vote sh ares to reflect the current distribution of economic power not lead to chaos? Would China not block loans to any country linked to the G7, and vice versa? Is not dysfunctional governance better than absolute paralysis?
Perhaps, which is why any reforms affecting countries’ voting power should be accompanied by a fundamental change in IMF governance. The executive board should no longer vote on operational decisions, including individual lending programs. Instead, the Fund’s top management should be given free rein to make operational decisions for the benefit of the global economy, with the board setting broad guidelines and periodically examining whether those guidelines have been met.
More to the point, the executive board should become a governance board, much as with corporations. It would set the organization’s operational mandate, and appoint and change management and monitor overall performance. However, it would not control day-to-day decisions. All operational decisions should be depoliticized. Indeed, that is what John Maynard Keynes would have preferred to see at the time of the Fund’s founding. Fearing the US’s undue influence, he proposed a non-resident board, which in those days of poor communications and steamship travel implied a non-executive board and an empowered management.
There are some foreseeable objections to this proposal. The first is that powerful countries would refuse to commit their taxpayers’ resources to the Fund unless they can exercise full control over their use. However, this is precisely what the dominant board powers already expect the rest of the world to do. What is good for the goose…
Another objection is that emerging powers such as China might not agree to a change in Fund structure now that they themselves are on the verge of acquiring power. However, if they do not accept any change, neither would the old powers. The recent 16th General Review of Quotas made little change in the distribution of board power. Expect more of the same unless the old powers and emerging powers reach a grand bargain.
Finally, countries would be uneasy with fiscal resources being spent by unelected management who could be insensitive to the needs of the world’s people. However, political considerations would still play a role. Board directors, appointed by governments, would appoint IMF top managers and give them broad marching orders, based on their governments’ political assessments. For example, the rules governing lending can become more lenient if the directors deem it appropriate. The difference is that the rules would be applied uniformly across all countries. Powerful friends of the needy can still help, but they would have to do so outside the Fund program, rather than by bending rules.
Eight decades after the IMF was created, the world can — and must — pursue a grand bargain to reform its governance structure and deal with emerging challenges. The alternative is to do little and watch the institution fade into irrelevance.
Raghuram G. Rajan, a former governor of the Reserve Bank of India and chief economist of the IMF, is professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and the co-author (with Rohit Lamba) of Breaking the Mold: India’s Untraveled Path to Prosperity (Princeton University Press, May 2024).
COpyright: Project Syndicate
Trying to force a partnership between Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Co (TSMC) and Intel Corp would be a wildly complex ordeal. Already, the reported request from the Trump administration for TSMC to take a controlling stake in Intel’s US factories is facing valid questions about feasibility from all sides. Washington would likely not support a foreign company operating Intel’s domestic factories, Reuters reported — just look at how that is going over in the steel sector. Meanwhile, many in Taiwan are concerned about the company being forced to transfer its bleeding-edge tech capabilities and give up its strategic advantage. This is especially
US President Donald Trump’s second administration has gotten off to a fast start with a blizzard of initiatives focused on domestic commitments made during his campaign. His tariff-based approach to re-ordering global trade in a manner more favorable to the United States appears to be in its infancy, but the significant scale and scope are undeniable. That said, while China looms largest on the list of national security challenges, to date we have heard little from the administration, bar the 10 percent tariffs directed at China, on specific priorities vis-a-vis China. The Congressional hearings for President Trump’s cabinet have, so far,
The US Department of State has removed the phrase “we do not support Taiwan independence” in its updated Taiwan-US relations fact sheet, which instead iterates that “we expect cross-strait differences to be resolved by peaceful means, free from coercion, in a manner acceptable to the people on both sides of the Strait.” This shows a tougher stance rejecting China’s false claims of sovereignty over Taiwan. Since switching formal diplomatic recognition from the Republic of China to the People’s Republic of China in 1979, the US government has continually indicated that it “does not support Taiwan independence.” The phrase was removed in 2022
US President Donald Trump, US Secretary of State Marco Rubio and US Secretary of Defense Pete Hegseth have each given their thoughts on Russia’s war with Ukraine. There are a few proponents of US skepticism in Taiwan taking advantage of developments to write articles claiming that the US would arbitrarily abandon Ukraine. The reality is that when one understands Trump’s negotiating habits, one sees that he brings up all variables of a situation prior to discussion, using broad negotiations to take charge. As for his ultimate goals and the aces up his sleeve, he wants to keep things vague for