British Chancellor of the Exchequer Rachel Reeves in a recent speech reiterated her commitment to “fiscal rules.” These rules require that “the current budget must move into balance” and that “the [national] debt must be falling as a share of the economy by [the Labour government’s] fifth year.”
This involves reducing the debt-to-GDP ratio from its current level of 100 percent within five years and eliminating the budget deficit, which stands at £121 billion (US$154 billion), or 4.4 percent of GDP.
At the same time, Labour has pledged to avoid significant tax hikes. Instead, the British government has opted for minor adjustments like abolishing the “non-domiciled” tax exemption for people who live in the UK, but declare a permanent residence in another country, imposing a 20 percent value-added tax on private-school fees and closing tax loopholes.
Consequently, the government must boost economic growth to meet its goals for deficit and debt reduction. While Labour aims to increase annual GDP growth to 2.5 percent (from an average of 1.1 percent from 2008 to last year), achieving this requires increased public investment. Notably, the UK spends less than most G7 countries.
To change this, the government plans to invest heavily in the green transition through the newly established Great British Energy and a planned British National Wealth Fund. However, given that its strict fiscal rules would inevitably constrain public investment, Labour’s economic agenda is more of a bet on growth than a strategy for growth.
Labour’s emphasis on fiscal rules represents the latest chapter in Britain’s ongoing tug-of-war between fiscal rules and discretion. During the Victorian era, British economic policy was built on three main pillars: the gold standard, which required the Bank of England to convert its notes to gold on demand at a fixed price; the balanced-budget rule, which ensured government spending was always covered by revenue; and the so-called “borrowing rule,” which established an annual sinking fund to retire debt, primarily incurred during wars. The economists of the time viewed war as the chief engine of debt build-up.
However, these pillars of “sound money” collapsed in the first half of the 20th century following the two world wars, the intervening Great Depression and the extension of the franchise. Enter John Maynard Keynes and the economics of discretion. Keynes’ liquidity-preference theory says when the future is uncertain, people generally prefer to keep their assets liquid rather than commit to projects that would generate returns at some undetermined future date.
Keynes believed that economic booms occurred only during periods of irrational exuberance and that the normal state of the capitalist economy was one of “underemployment equilibrium.” The solution lay not in “abolishing booms and thus keeping us permanently in a semi-slump,” but in “abolishing slumps and thus keeping us permanently in a quasi-boom.” The mechanism for achieving this was autonomous investment by the state, which would bridge the gap between what banks were willing to lend and what borrowers were willing to invest.
Keynesian economic policies were discretionary: Fixed exchange rates became “adjustable pegs,” budgetary policy depended on employment levels, and the government would tell the Bank of England what interest rates to set. Despite the reliance on massive increases in public spending to meet growing welfare entitlements, the Keynesian era proved to be a huge success. From the mid-1940s to the mid-1970s, the UK enjoyed full employment, annual growth rates averaging 2-to-3 percent, rising GDP per capita, and stable inflation. As then-British prime minister Harold Macmillan famously remarked in 1957, Britons “never had it so good.”
The situation began to deteriorate in the late 1960s. While this was arguably the result of external shocks like the Vietnam War and the quadrupling of oil prices rather than hubris on the part of Keynesian policymakers, skyrocketing inflation and growing industrial disorder ultimately set the stage for Milton Friedman’s monetarism and the return of fiscal rules. Monetary policy would be entrusted to independent central banks tasked with securing low and stable inflation. Without strict fiscal rules, a competitive democracy would inevitably lead to excessive public spending, a new generation of political economists said.
Consequently, the budget needed to be “balanced over the business cycle,” and government debt as a share of GDP had to remain low.
These new rules, essentially modified versions of Victorian-era principles, led to two reasonably good decades in the 1990s and 2000s. Then came the great financial crash of 2007 and 2008, from which the British economy and most of its European counterparts have never completely recovered.
It seems that whether you try to steady economies by discretion as Keynes suggests or by rules of Friedman, you ultimately mess up. Promises to “get the economy moving” are invariably followed by economic crises. There is no clear explanation for this, except perhaps that mediocrity is humanity’s lot.
Two reflections are pertinent to Reeves’ dilemma. Britain’s problem is not a lack of money — the financial system is awash with the money created by quantitative easing — but underinvestment. Today’s risk-averse climate can be read as a vindication of Keynes’ liquidity preference story. So public investment is needed to “crowd in” reluctant private investment.
The other crucial point is geopolitics. The US-style Keynesianism that faltered during the Vietnam War was “military Keynesianism” — borrowing and rising debt were justified by the demands of the Cold War and the arms race with the Soviet Union. Fiscal rules were subordinated to the need to “contain” the enemy, and national-security demands always had ample resources to draw from.
Labour’s stated mission is to make Britain greener. I suspect it would end up focusing on making the country safer rather than greener, with borrowing to “get Britain moving” justified not on economic grounds but in the name of national security.
This is a dispiriting prospect. Given the history of the rules-versus-discretion debate, it is hard to believe in British Prime Minister Keir Starmer’s promised new dawn.
Robert Skidelsky, a member of the British House of Lords, is professor emeritus of political economy at Warwick University. He is the author of an award-winning biography of John Maynard Keynes and The Machine Age: An Idea, a History, a Warning.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
As Taiwan’s domestic political crisis deepens, the opposition Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and Taiwan People’s Party (TPP) have proposed gutting the country’s national spending, with steep cuts to the critical foreign and defense ministries. While the blue-white coalition alleges that it is merely responding to voters’ concerns about corruption and mismanagement, of which there certainly has been plenty under Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) and KMT-led governments, the rationales for their proposed spending cuts lay bare the incoherent foreign policy of the KMT-led coalition. Introduced on the eve of US President Donald Trump’s inauguration, the KMT’s proposed budget is a terrible opening
The Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) caucus in the Legislative Yuan has made an internal decision to freeze NT$1.8 billion (US$54.7 million) of the indigenous submarine project’s NT$2 billion budget. This means that up to 90 percent of the budget cannot be utilized. It would only be accessible if the legislature agrees to lift the freeze sometime in the future. However, for Taiwan to construct its own submarines, it must rely on foreign support for several key pieces of equipment and technology. These foreign supporters would also be forced to endure significant pressure, infiltration and influence from Beijing. In other words,
“I compare the Communist Party to my mother,” sings a student at a boarding school in a Tibetan region of China’s Qinghai province. “If faith has a color,” others at a different school sing, “it would surely be Chinese red.” In a major story for the New York Times this month, Chris Buckley wrote about the forced placement of hundreds of thousands of Tibetan children in boarding schools, where many suffer physical and psychological abuse. Separating these children from their families, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) aims to substitute itself for their parents and for their religion. Buckley’s reporting is
Last week, the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party (TPP), together holding more than half of the legislative seats, cut about NT$94 billion (US$2.85 billion) from the yearly budget. The cuts include 60 percent of the government’s advertising budget, 10 percent of administrative expenses, 3 percent of the military budget, and 60 percent of the international travel, overseas education and training allowances. In addition, the two parties have proposed freezing the budgets of many ministries and departments, including NT$1.8 billion from the Ministry of National Defense’s Indigenous Defense Submarine program — 90 percent of the program’s proposed