In many countries, the political landscape is changing dramatically, possibly auguring more radical policies in the US and Europe. Faced with societal aging, deglobalization, climate change, anti-immigration sentiment and technological advances, central banks will feel pressure from many directions in the next few years.
One obvious concern is fiscal policy and debt. When radical politicians come to power, they rarely have austerity in mind. Most arrive with big, audacious plans requiring massive increases in spending. Argentine President Javier Milei is an exception, in part because he was elected to reverse the policies of the previous radicals.
However, moderate leaders also will feel greater pressure to spend in the years ahead. Real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates are likely to return to their long-term trend, which means debt-service costs will eat up more of governments’ budgets. Military spending also will undoubtedly rise, given the state of geopolitics, and spending on education will probably have to increase as governments try to position their populations for an era of artificial intelligence (AI).
Illustration: Mountain People
On top of it all, climate-related spending and subsidies have become more urgent. Political dysfunction makes it hard to tax emissions, which would be more fiscally prudent, or raise tax revenues more generally.
All this additional net spending implies that central banks will have to offset governments’ expansionary impulses with tighter policy, but with many countries already heavily indebted, sustained higher real policy rates will fuel doubt about debt sustainability.
Will central banks blink and allow higher price growth, in the hope of inflating away some of the debt? Or will they stand up to their respective governments and raise rates?
When fiscal priorities and debt levels determine the scope of monetary policy, economists call it “fiscal dominance.” We are likely to see more cases of this.
What about demographic trends? UK-based economists Charles Goodhart and Manoj Pradhan believe that with the Chinese working-age population shrinking, and populations aging elsewhere, growth will slow as the labor force declines.
Meanwhile, spending will rise — partly to meet the need for more elder care — and wage growth might strengthen as workers become scarce. All this will be inflationary.
Of course, others believe that savings will rise with aging, and that immigration into aging countries will help stave off labor shortages, but given many aging countries’ open refusal to accept a large number of immigrants, this optimistic scenario seems less likely.
Ever since then-US president Donald Trump imposed sweeping tariffs on imports from China, we have been witnessing a broad-based return of protectionism, translating first into lower cross-border investment. So far, trade has held up, partly because Chinese inputs are being shipped for final assembly to other countries before being sent to the US, but if Trump returns to the White House in January next year, he will try to end such transshipments while raising tariffs all around.
Deglobalization will continue to increase the price of foreign goods, but whether this process is inflationary might depend on how the process unfolds. As economists Ludovica Ambrosino, Jenny Chan and Silvana Tenreyro note in ongoing work, if the tariffs are sudden, inflation will spike significantly and central banks will find it hard to avoid hiking interest rates.
In the medium term, the researchers said, domestic importers will shift to alternative suppliers, and because the economy will be poorer and consumption lower — with each dollar of spending buying fewer imports — inflation will taper off.
Interestingly, if the higher import prices kick in more gradually, falling demand in anticipation of higher import prices could lead to a slowdown in inflation for domestic goods, keeping overall inflation contained. Thus, protectionism might increase import prices; but because it also makes us poorer and depresses demand, it might not increase inflation much.
This relatively benign view must be set against our experience in the decades of globalization before the global financial crisis, when inflation fell worldwide. If globalization brought down inflation, should it not be that deglobalization raises it?
This is what economists Hassan Afrouzi, Kenneth Rogoff and Pierre Yared, and author Marina Halac said. Deglobalization, by reducing competition, will boost monopoly profits and thus increase central banks’ temptation to allow for more inflation as a means of eroding those profits and sustaining labor’s share of output.
Of course, deglobalization could also increase union power, which, under the same assumptions, should mitigate this temptation, but given that globalization was accompanied by lower inflation, we should at least prepare for the possibility that deglobalization will do the opposite.
The transition to a low-carbon economy will further complicate the picture. As ongoing work by economists Luca Fornaro, Veronica Guerrieri and Lucrezia Reichlin suggests, green regulations typically impose additional costs on dirty energy sources, sometimes to the point that banks will not even fund such projects.
However, as long as dirty energy is a necessary production input, output that relies on it will be costlier. When demand rises, firms will have to use more dirty energy, increasing costs and output prices further.
To contain inflation, central bank policies will have to be much tighter and that will mean slower growth. It also might slow the shift in demand toward green energy and inhibit investment in renewables, which in the medium term would alleviate dependence on fossil fuels. Faced with this prospect, green-oriented central banks might reasonably want to be more tolerant of higher inflation to facilitate the green transition.
Most of the forces and dynamics push toward higher inflation. True, if productivity increases as a result of technological advances like the widespread implementation of AI, inflationary pressures could ease because of greater, cheaper supply.
However, at this point this is more of a hope than a reality.
Perhaps the greatest worry is that with electorates demanding a change, radical leaders will create the conditions for higher inflation — for instance, by stopping immigration or spending without restraint — even as they erode the independence of central banks. That happened regularly in the past and the consequences were not pretty.
We might have to relearn old lessons the hard way.
Raghuram G. Rajan, a former governor of the Reserve Bank of India and chief economist of the IMF, is a professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
The US election result will significantly impact its foreign policy with global implications. As tensions escalate in the Taiwan Strait and conflicts elsewhere draw attention away from the western Pacific, Taiwan was closely monitoring the election, as many believe that whoever won would confront an increasingly assertive China, especially with speculation over a potential escalation in or around 2027. A second Donald Trump presidency naturally raises questions concerning the future of US policy toward China and Taiwan, with Trump displaying mixed signals as to his position on the cross-strait conflict. US foreign policy would also depend on Trump’s Cabinet and
The Taiwanese have proven to be resilient in the face of disasters and they have resisted continuing attempts to subordinate Taiwan to the People’s Republic of China (PRC). Nonetheless, the Taiwanese can and should do more to become even more resilient and to be better prepared for resistance should the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) try to annex Taiwan. President William Lai (賴清德) argues that the Taiwanese should determine their own fate. This position continues the Democratic Progressive Party’s (DPP) tradition of opposing the CCP’s annexation of Taiwan. Lai challenges the CCP’s narrative by stating that Taiwan is not subordinate to the
Republican candidate and former US president Donald Trump is to be the 47th president of the US after beating his Democratic rival, US Vice President Kamala Harris, in the election on Tuesday. Trump’s thumping victory — winning 295 Electoral College votes against Harris’ 226 as of press time last night, along with the Republicans winning control of the US Senate and possibly the House of Representatives — is a remarkable political comeback from his 2020 defeat to US President Joe Biden, and means Trump has a strong political mandate to implement his agenda. What does Trump’s victory mean for Taiwan, Asia, deterrence
The return of US president-elect Donald Trump to the White House has injected a new wave of anxiety across the Taiwan Strait. For Taiwan, an island whose very survival depends on the delicate and strategic support from the US, Trump’s election victory raises a cascade of questions and fears about what lies ahead. His approach to international relations — grounded in transactional and unpredictable policies — poses unique risks to Taiwan’s stability, economic prosperity and geopolitical standing. Trump’s first term left a complicated legacy in the region. On the one hand, his administration ramped up arms sales to Taiwan and sanctioned