In many countries, the political landscape is changing dramatically, possibly auguring more radical policies in the US and Europe. Faced with societal aging, deglobalization, climate change, anti-immigration sentiment and technological advances, central banks will feel pressure from many directions in the next few years.
One obvious concern is fiscal policy and debt. When radical politicians come to power, they rarely have austerity in mind. Most arrive with big, audacious plans requiring massive increases in spending. Argentine President Javier Milei is an exception, in part because he was elected to reverse the policies of the previous radicals.
However, moderate leaders also will feel greater pressure to spend in the years ahead. Real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates are likely to return to their long-term trend, which means debt-service costs will eat up more of governments’ budgets. Military spending also will undoubtedly rise, given the state of geopolitics, and spending on education will probably have to increase as governments try to position their populations for an era of artificial intelligence (AI).
Illustration: Mountain People
On top of it all, climate-related spending and subsidies have become more urgent. Political dysfunction makes it hard to tax emissions, which would be more fiscally prudent, or raise tax revenues more generally.
All this additional net spending implies that central banks will have to offset governments’ expansionary impulses with tighter policy, but with many countries already heavily indebted, sustained higher real policy rates will fuel doubt about debt sustainability.
Will central banks blink and allow higher price growth, in the hope of inflating away some of the debt? Or will they stand up to their respective governments and raise rates?
When fiscal priorities and debt levels determine the scope of monetary policy, economists call it “fiscal dominance.” We are likely to see more cases of this.
What about demographic trends? UK-based economists Charles Goodhart and Manoj Pradhan believe that with the Chinese working-age population shrinking, and populations aging elsewhere, growth will slow as the labor force declines.
Meanwhile, spending will rise — partly to meet the need for more elder care — and wage growth might strengthen as workers become scarce. All this will be inflationary.
Of course, others believe that savings will rise with aging, and that immigration into aging countries will help stave off labor shortages, but given many aging countries’ open refusal to accept a large number of immigrants, this optimistic scenario seems less likely.
Ever since then-US president Donald Trump imposed sweeping tariffs on imports from China, we have been witnessing a broad-based return of protectionism, translating first into lower cross-border investment. So far, trade has held up, partly because Chinese inputs are being shipped for final assembly to other countries before being sent to the US, but if Trump returns to the White House in January next year, he will try to end such transshipments while raising tariffs all around.
Deglobalization will continue to increase the price of foreign goods, but whether this process is inflationary might depend on how the process unfolds. As economists Ludovica Ambrosino, Jenny Chan and Silvana Tenreyro note in ongoing work, if the tariffs are sudden, inflation will spike significantly and central banks will find it hard to avoid hiking interest rates.
In the medium term, the researchers said, domestic importers will shift to alternative suppliers, and because the economy will be poorer and consumption lower — with each dollar of spending buying fewer imports — inflation will taper off.
Interestingly, if the higher import prices kick in more gradually, falling demand in anticipation of higher import prices could lead to a slowdown in inflation for domestic goods, keeping overall inflation contained. Thus, protectionism might increase import prices; but because it also makes us poorer and depresses demand, it might not increase inflation much.
This relatively benign view must be set against our experience in the decades of globalization before the global financial crisis, when inflation fell worldwide. If globalization brought down inflation, should it not be that deglobalization raises it?
This is what economists Hassan Afrouzi, Kenneth Rogoff and Pierre Yared, and author Marina Halac said. Deglobalization, by reducing competition, will boost monopoly profits and thus increase central banks’ temptation to allow for more inflation as a means of eroding those profits and sustaining labor’s share of output.
Of course, deglobalization could also increase union power, which, under the same assumptions, should mitigate this temptation, but given that globalization was accompanied by lower inflation, we should at least prepare for the possibility that deglobalization will do the opposite.
The transition to a low-carbon economy will further complicate the picture. As ongoing work by economists Luca Fornaro, Veronica Guerrieri and Lucrezia Reichlin suggests, green regulations typically impose additional costs on dirty energy sources, sometimes to the point that banks will not even fund such projects.
However, as long as dirty energy is a necessary production input, output that relies on it will be costlier. When demand rises, firms will have to use more dirty energy, increasing costs and output prices further.
To contain inflation, central bank policies will have to be much tighter and that will mean slower growth. It also might slow the shift in demand toward green energy and inhibit investment in renewables, which in the medium term would alleviate dependence on fossil fuels. Faced with this prospect, green-oriented central banks might reasonably want to be more tolerant of higher inflation to facilitate the green transition.
Most of the forces and dynamics push toward higher inflation. True, if productivity increases as a result of technological advances like the widespread implementation of AI, inflationary pressures could ease because of greater, cheaper supply.
However, at this point this is more of a hope than a reality.
Perhaps the greatest worry is that with electorates demanding a change, radical leaders will create the conditions for higher inflation — for instance, by stopping immigration or spending without restraint — even as they erode the independence of central banks. That happened regularly in the past and the consequences were not pretty.
We might have to relearn old lessons the hard way.
Raghuram G. Rajan, a former governor of the Reserve Bank of India and chief economist of the IMF, is a professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
As Taiwan’s domestic political crisis deepens, the opposition Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and Taiwan People’s Party (TPP) have proposed gutting the country’s national spending, with steep cuts to the critical foreign and defense ministries. While the blue-white coalition alleges that it is merely responding to voters’ concerns about corruption and mismanagement, of which there certainly has been plenty under Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) and KMT-led governments, the rationales for their proposed spending cuts lay bare the incoherent foreign policy of the KMT-led coalition. Introduced on the eve of US President Donald Trump’s inauguration, the KMT’s proposed budget is a terrible opening
The Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) caucus in the Legislative Yuan has made an internal decision to freeze NT$1.8 billion (US$54.7 million) of the indigenous submarine project’s NT$2 billion budget. This means that up to 90 percent of the budget cannot be utilized. It would only be accessible if the legislature agrees to lift the freeze sometime in the future. However, for Taiwan to construct its own submarines, it must rely on foreign support for several key pieces of equipment and technology. These foreign supporters would also be forced to endure significant pressure, infiltration and influence from Beijing. In other words,
“I compare the Communist Party to my mother,” sings a student at a boarding school in a Tibetan region of China’s Qinghai province. “If faith has a color,” others at a different school sing, “it would surely be Chinese red.” In a major story for the New York Times this month, Chris Buckley wrote about the forced placement of hundreds of thousands of Tibetan children in boarding schools, where many suffer physical and psychological abuse. Separating these children from their families, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) aims to substitute itself for their parents and for their religion. Buckley’s reporting is
Last week, the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party (TPP), together holding more than half of the legislative seats, cut about NT$94 billion (US$2.85 billion) from the yearly budget. The cuts include 60 percent of the government’s advertising budget, 10 percent of administrative expenses, 3 percent of the military budget, and 60 percent of the international travel, overseas education and training allowances. In addition, the two parties have proposed freezing the budgets of many ministries and departments, including NT$1.8 billion from the Ministry of National Defense’s Indigenous Defense Submarine program — 90 percent of the program’s proposed