As the global fertility crisis continues to accelerate, so does the anxiety over what to do about it. A smaller world population might be fine in the short run, but it would not be good for it to asymptotically approach zero, and many citizens presumably do not want their countries to lose their geopolitical influence due to population decline. In many cases, there is also national debt to be paid off, which requires more young people to pay taxes and finance the pensions of the old.
Some countries are taking action. South Korea, which has the world’s lowest total fertility rate — just above 0.7, far below the replacement level of 2.1 — is pondering a radical solution: baby bonuses of 100 million won (US$73,500) each. For perspective, that is about twice South Korea’s annual per capita income. At current birthrates, the plan would cost more than US$16 billion a year; if it is successful, it would cost even more.
In principle, these kinds of policies are self-financing.
Illustration: Yusha
Most babies born today or over the next few years would grow up to be taxpayers. In the long run, the birth subsidies in net terms need not cost anything at all. If, for instance, you pay two years’ average income to a family to have another child, you might plausibly expect to later receive about 45 years of tax receipts.
Would such policies actually result in population growth? After all, the government might end up making a lot of payments to families which would have had children anyway. Imagine that, after putting the policy into practice, only one-10th of the kids born were induced by the subsidy. In that case, in expected value terms, the two years’ investment of per capita income yields only one-10th of the calculation presented above — that is, 4.5 years of additional tax receipts. Given that those receipts are discounted for a rather distant future, and perhaps constitute only about one-third of income, in fiscal terms this is not a profitable deal.
You might think it is worth spending money to increase the number of South Korean babies. After all, people in prosperous countries are on average happy, and that is worthwhile in itself, aside from their contribution to the public till. Still, if addressing public budget imbalances is one of the motivations for this policy, it could make fiscal problems worse.
Unfortunately, it is impossible to say how much impact the subsidies would have, as there is no precedent. The closest would be Hungary’s subsidies for childbearing, including income tax exemptions amounting to about 5 percent of GDP. These policies were instituted only a few years ago, but there is some evidence of rising fertility rates in Hungary, albeit at 1.6, still well below the replacement rate.
When birth subsidies get smaller, most of the evidence is not encouraging. The Nordic countries provide various kinds of free childcare and benefits for parents, such as paid work leave. Those policies are generous by global standards, yet the resulting birthrates are not impressive.
Similarly, data from the US shows that the so-called “shifting priorities” of younger generations — about life choices and societal norms — influence decisions about family size far more than any changes in childrearing costs or subsidies.
France also has a subsidy plan in mind, but it probably is not big enough to work. Singapore has tried subsidies as well as nudges, such as government-sponsored dating cruises, to no avail.
It should not be a huge surprise that the smaller subsidies do not work.
Having children changes everything you do and how you do it. If you are not interested in that life-altering transformation, a birth subsidy is not going to make a difference. Subsidies might convince a couple with two children to have a third, because now the additional child is easier to afford. The problem of course is that so many families are not having two children to begin with.
Peer expectations are another factor here. If most families have three children, more people might seek to meet that standard and the subsidy could help them do so. One way the subsidies could work is by creating a critical mass of large families and changing social norms for everyone.
In any case, the South Korean and Hungarian birth subsidy experiments deserve both praise and scrutiny. Even if they just slow, but do not arrest the trend toward much older and smaller societies, they are still worth pursuing.
We all would learn from the results. There is not enough social experimentation in the world, and humanity has to try something to avoid disappearing.
Tyler Cowen is a Bloomberg Opinion columnist, a professor of economics at George Mason University and host of the Marginal Revolution blog.
Trying to force a partnership between Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Co (TSMC) and Intel Corp would be a wildly complex ordeal. Already, the reported request from the Trump administration for TSMC to take a controlling stake in Intel’s US factories is facing valid questions about feasibility from all sides. Washington would likely not support a foreign company operating Intel’s domestic factories, Reuters reported — just look at how that is going over in the steel sector. Meanwhile, many in Taiwan are concerned about the company being forced to transfer its bleeding-edge tech capabilities and give up its strategic advantage. This is especially
US President Donald Trump’s second administration has gotten off to a fast start with a blizzard of initiatives focused on domestic commitments made during his campaign. His tariff-based approach to re-ordering global trade in a manner more favorable to the United States appears to be in its infancy, but the significant scale and scope are undeniable. That said, while China looms largest on the list of national security challenges, to date we have heard little from the administration, bar the 10 percent tariffs directed at China, on specific priorities vis-a-vis China. The Congressional hearings for President Trump’s cabinet have, so far,
The US Department of State has removed the phrase “we do not support Taiwan independence” in its updated Taiwan-US relations fact sheet, which instead iterates that “we expect cross-strait differences to be resolved by peaceful means, free from coercion, in a manner acceptable to the people on both sides of the Strait.” This shows a tougher stance rejecting China’s false claims of sovereignty over Taiwan. Since switching formal diplomatic recognition from the Republic of China to the People’s Republic of China in 1979, the US government has continually indicated that it “does not support Taiwan independence.” The phrase was removed in 2022
US President Donald Trump, US Secretary of State Marco Rubio and US Secretary of Defense Pete Hegseth have each given their thoughts on Russia’s war with Ukraine. There are a few proponents of US skepticism in Taiwan taking advantage of developments to write articles claiming that the US would arbitrarily abandon Ukraine. The reality is that when one understands Trump’s negotiating habits, one sees that he brings up all variables of a situation prior to discussion, using broad negotiations to take charge. As for his ultimate goals and the aces up his sleeve, he wants to keep things vague for