The widening debt crisis in the global south largely emanates from a flawed multilateral system. However, it also reflects the inadequacies of the dominant analytical and policy frameworks — specifically, their assumptions about the nature of money, the economic possibilities available to currency-issuing governments and the underlying causes of developing countries’ external indebtedness.
Viewed through the lens of modern monetary theory (MMT), the limitations of mainstream economic thinking as applied to sovereign-debt crises become even clearer. The basic idea behind MMT is that, unlike households or private firms, governments that control their own fiat currency cannot default — assuming that their debt is denominated in their own currency. As they are not money-constrained, they could spend to achieve their goals. Their main constraint is the availability of productive capacity, which determines the risk of inflation.
MMT explains why the most indebted countries, in absolute and relative terms, are not in distress. Consider that Japan’s sovereign debt-to-GDP ratio was 254 percent last year, while the ratio was 144 percent in the US, 113 percent in Canada and 104 percent in the UK. Yet none of these countries is experiencing a sovereign-debt crisis. By contrast, in 2020, Argentina, Ecuador and Zambia had much lower debt-to-GDP ratios when they defaulted on their external obligations.
The main difference is that Japan, the US, Canada and the UK are monetarily sovereign: Their public debt is denominated in their national currency, while their central banks maintain some control over the interest rates applied to that debt. Most governments in the global south are at risk of insolvency because they borrowed in foreign currencies.
MMT implies that if rich countries desired to provide significant debt relief to the global south, the main challenges would be coordination — between different creditors and debtors, as well as other relevant actors — and accountability, not affordability. Given that these countries cannot run out of their own currency, there are no financial constraints on canceling in whole or in part the public and publicly guaranteed external debt stock of 131 lower and middle-income countries, excluding China, Russia and India. This debt stood at US$2.6 trillion in 2022 — an amount less than Germany’s public debt.
Why do global south countries that are in or at risk of debt distress borrow in foreign currencies in the first place?
Economists’ usual answer is that these countries would otherwise lack “money” and “savings.” Such a view is based on an erroneous understanding of the nature of money. Currency-issuing governments cannot run out of their own money.
Moreover, as the Bank of England has shown, banks are not intermediaries between savers and loan applicants; instead, they create new purchasing power every time they extend a loan.
This leads to another important observation derived from MMT: As money is not scarce, anything that is technically and materially feasible at the national level could be financed in the national currency. Developing countries need not issue foreign-currency debt to finance projects that require locally available resources such as labor, land, raw materials, equipment and technologies.
When required resources are not locally available and could only be purchased with foreign currencies, developing countries might be forced to take on the burden of US dollar-denominated debt. One could imagine resource-poor or climate-vulnerable countries making such a choice.
However, this ignores the fact that global south countries often earn substantial income from exports. The issue is that a significant proportion of this income is remitted back to foreign investors — many of whom benefit from an inequitable global tax architecture — as profits or dividends. This is on top of the fraudulent practices that result in illicit financial flows.
Between 2000 and 2018, for example, African countries suffered greater financial hardship from profit transfers by foreign investors, dividend repatriation by subsidiaries to their parent companies and illicit financial flows than from servicing external debt. They issued foreign-currency debt that paid high-interest rates partly to plug the gap created by foreign nationals appropriating — both legally and illegally — vast US dollar earnings.
Consider Zambia, a copper-producing country that lost around US$10.6 billion in the form of illicit financial flows between 1970 and 1996 (355 percent of its GDP in 1996), US$8.8 billion between 2001 and 2010, and US$12.5 billion between 2013 and 2015. Zambia’s public and publicly guaranteed external debt was US$1.2 billion in 2010, rising to US$12.5 billion by 2021.
If the Zambian government had better fiscal and technical control over its export sector, it would have accumulated sufficient US dollar reserves to enhance food and energy self-sufficiency, and to finance investment in infrastructure and other public goods requiring the import of foreign productive capacity. There would have been no need to take on so much foreign currency debt. The same could be said for other resource-rich African countries.
In a just world, countries subject to asymmetric tax agreements and resource theft would be fairly compensated, rather than crushed by austerity policies.
Barring that, external debt cancellation would help developing countries invest in climate resilience and improve the health and well-being of their populations. As many policymakers, economists and social movements have argued, it is an urgent necessity.
Yet even such a bold step would not be enough to address the root causes of recurring debt crises in the global south. That would require stopping the financial bleeding caused by multinational corporations and promoting an economic development strategy that makes full use of the resources each country can command with its national currency.
Ndongo Samba Sylla, head of research and policy for Africa at International Development Economics Associates, is a former technical adviser to the president of the Republic of Senegal and a co-author of Africa’s Last Colonial Currency: The CFA Franc Story and a co-editor of Economic and Monetary Sovereignty in 21st Century Africa.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
Would China attack Taiwan during the American lame duck period? For months, there have been worries that Beijing would seek to take advantage of an American president slowed by age and a potentially chaotic transition to make a move on Taiwan. In the wake of an American election that ended without drama, that far-fetched scenario will likely prove purely hypothetical. But there is a crisis brewing elsewhere in Asia — one with which US president-elect Donald Trump may have to deal during his first days in office. Tensions between the Philippines and China in the South China Sea have been at
Russian President Vladimir Putin’s hypersonic missile carried a simple message to the West over Ukraine: Back off, and if you do not, Russia reserves the right to hit US and British military facilities. Russia fired a new intermediate-range hypersonic ballistic missile known as “Oreshnik,” or Hazel Tree, at Ukraine on Thursday in what Putin said was a direct response to strikes on Russia by Ukrainian forces with US and British missiles. In a special statement from the Kremlin just after 8pm in Moscow that day, the Russian president said the war was escalating toward a global conflict, although he avoided any nuclear
A nation has several pillars of national defense, among them are military strength, energy and food security, and national unity. Military strength is very much on the forefront of the debate, while several recent editorials have dealt with energy security. National unity and a sense of shared purpose — especially while a powerful, hostile state is becoming increasingly menacing — are problematic, and would continue to be until the nation’s schizophrenia is properly managed. The controversy over the past few days over former navy lieutenant commander Lu Li-shih’s (呂禮詩) usage of the term “our China” during an interview about his attendance
Bo Guagua (薄瓜瓜), the son of former Chinese Communist Party (CCP) Central Committee Politburo member and former Chongqing Municipal Communist Party secretary Bo Xilai (薄熙來), used his British passport to make a low-key entry into Taiwan on a flight originating in Canada. He is set to marry the granddaughter of former political heavyweight Hsu Wen-cheng (許文政), the founder of Luodong Poh-Ai Hospital in Yilan County’s Luodong Township (羅東). Bo Xilai is a former high-ranking CCP official who was once a challenger to Chinese President Xi Jinping (習近平) for the chairmanship of the CCP. That makes Bo Guagua a bona fide “third-generation red”