Contrary to initial expectations, the spread of COVID-19 around the world is not following the relatively benign trajectories experienced in China outside of Wuhan and Hubei Province, and in South Korea, Singapore and the rest of Asia. Instead, across Europe — and likely in the US, too — the spread of the virus increasingly resembles the path it took in Hubei.
This threatens to create a medical and economic disaster. While it might be too late for policymakers to avert a public-health crisis, it is still possible to implement the fiscal and monetary measures needed to prevent an economic catastrophe.
To do this, they need to go much further than the monetary steps announced by the US Federal Reserve and the proposals from US President Donald Trump’s administration for untargeted tax cuts and cash handouts thus far.
Illustration: Mountain People
Initially, the number of cases in EU countries was expected to converge toward the 10 to 100 patients per million seen in Asia outside Hubei, and that the US might follow a similar pattern.
However, Italy, France, Spain and other EU countries are not experiencing the slowdown in the rate of change of acceleration (the second derivative of velocity, or the “jolt” in mathematical parlance), seen in Wuhan and the rest of China by this stage in the epidemic.
One possible explanation is that Italy’s lockdown measures are much less rigorous than those in Asia, and that healthcare systems are less prepared. For example, patients are not removed from their families as quickly, and so infect others.
If so, then the acceleration in the US and the UK would be even more rapid than in continental Europe, because of the piecemeal, and plain misguided, policy responses from Trump and British Prime Minister Boris Johnson.
It is thus entirely possible that the asymptotic outcome for countries in Europe and the US would be more like Wuhan’s 1,000 cases per million.
Alternatively, in what a few weeks ago would have seemed a nightmare fantasy, but is now a reasonable worst-case scenario, Europe and the US could end up with far more infections per capita than Wuhan.
Italy, with confirmed infections of more than 69,000 in a population of about 60 million, already is approaching Wuhan’s ratio — and the Italian epidemic still appears to be accelerating rapidly at a stage when Wuhan’s was already slowing down.
Meanwhile, the British government publicly contemplated, and then backtracked from, a policy that would allow the virus to infect 60 percent of the population in the hope of establishing “herd immunity.” This would be a rate of infection 600 times the level in Wuhan.
The only good news in this dreadful situation is that, unlike the medical effects of the virus, the economic impact is easy to predict and overcome.
There is one possible policy response that could prevent the pandemic, even in the relatively virulent form experienced in Hubei, from fueling an economic catastrophe worse than the 2008 financial crisis.
Governments in every major economy must guarantee unlimited compensation for lost revenues and wages to all businesses and workers affected by quarantines and lockdowns — if not the full 100 percent, then maybe 80 to 90 percent.
Ideally, this compensation would come through outright grants and fiscal transfers, but another option for larger businesses might be long-term zero-interest loans or loan guarantees.
Luckily, this response is now feasible because of the way the 2008 crisis transformed the world economy and financial markets, offering governments unlimited financing with zero interest rates, low inflation and tolerance for previously unthinkable monetary and fiscal experimentation.
To be clear, in the current situation, monetary policy would not do anything to stimulate economic activity. Nor do policymakers want it to: More economic activity now would only aggravate the public-health crisis.
However, zero rates and huge liquidity injections are still necessary to prevent financial systems from collapsing.
Fiscal measures designed to support recovery should wait until the virus is under control.
What governments can and should do now is reassure their citizens and businesses that they can stay at home and not worry about lost incomes, because the government will make up for the losses once the crisis is over.
Based on China’s experience, the fiscal cost of comprehensive compensation for lost income could easily come to 10 percent of annual GDP. If the epidemic turned out to be worse than in China, which now looks likely, the fiscal cost could be as high as 25 percent of GDP.
These might seem like mind-boggling numbers, but they could be financed in one or more of three ways.
First, every G20 country, with the possible exception of Italy, could easily increase its government debt-to-GDP ratio by 25 percentage points without raising any serious questions about solvency.
Debt-service costs would hardly rise at all if central banks committed to keeping short rates at zero for at least two years, and investors were forced by regulation and financial repression to match liabilities with long maturities.
There is a fundamental difference between a one-off fiscal transfer, however large, and fiscal stimulus through tax cuts or spending commitments that permanently increase annual deficits.
A one-off transfer of 25 percent of GDP does less damage to long-term fiscal solvency than a tax cut of 1 percent or 2 percent of GDP or long-term spending commitments that change the fiscal structure for decades ahead.
Second, central banks could increase their quantitative easing programs to absorb the entire additional debt issuance. In short, the monetary base in every G7 economy could simply expand by 25 percent of GDP.
Lastly, compensation for businesses and workers could come directly from central banks through targeted drops of “helicopter” money.
Agreement among governments and central banks around the world on a single method would boost the credibility of the response. However, in practice, some combination of these three policies could be employed.
Still, there are two objections to full government compensation: It could ultimately prove inflationary, and it would represent an unprecedented intervention by governments to bail out and subsidize businesses.
These are weak objections. Today, everyone wants higher inflation. While this might eventually — maybe by the second half of the decade — turn out to be a mistake, there would be plenty of time to switch to anti-inflationary policies between now and then.
Full compensation is far from unprecedented. Farmers are regularly compensated for agricultural disasters, such as mad cow disease, or even for plunging agricultural prices and trade disputes. Regions and households affected by floods, earthquakes or wildfires are normally compensated through disaster relief or subsidized insurance.
Since 2008, banks, insurance companies and financial markets have received effective fiscal transfers in many countries amounting to far more than 25 percent of GDP.
The difference in this case is that the disaster affects everyone, which, in principle, makes the case for compensation stronger.
The only reason why governments around the world are still thinking in terms of loans and credit guarantees, instead of direct fiscal compensation, is that no special-interest lobby such as farmers or bankers is demanding targeted relief.
Anatole Kaletsky, a former columnist for the Times of London, the International New York Times and the Financial Times, is chief economist and cochairman of Gavekal Dragonomics.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
Labubu, an elf-like plush toy with pointy ears and nine serrated teeth, has become a global sensation, worn by celebrities including Rihanna and Dua Lipa. These dolls are sold out in stores from Singapore to London; a human-sized version recently fetched a whopping US$150,000 at an auction in Beijing. With all the social media buzz, it is worth asking if we are witnessing the rise of a new-age collectible, or whether Labubu is a mere fad destined to fade. Investors certainly want to know. Pop Mart International Group Ltd, the Chinese manufacturer behind this trendy toy, has rallied 178 percent
My youngest son attends a university in Taipei. Throughout the past two years, whenever I have brought him his luggage or picked him up for the end of a semester or the start of a break, I have stayed at a hotel near his campus. In doing so, I have noticed a strange phenomenon: The hotel’s TV contained an unusual number of Chinese channels, filled with accents that would make a person feel as if they are in China. It is quite exhausting. A few days ago, while staying in the hotel, I found that of the 50 available TV channels,
Kinmen County’s political geography is provocative in and of itself. A pair of islets running up abreast the Chinese mainland, just 20 minutes by ferry from the Chinese city of Xiamen, Kinmen remains under the Taiwanese government’s control, after China’s failed invasion attempt in 1949. The provocative nature of Kinmen’s existence, along with the Matsu Islands off the coast of China’s Fuzhou City, has led to no shortage of outrageous takes and analyses in foreign media either fearmongering of a Chinese invasion or using these accidents of history to somehow understand Taiwan. Every few months a foreign reporter goes to
There is no such thing as a “silicon shield.” This trope has gained traction in the world of Taiwanese news, likely with the best intentions. Anything that breaks the China-controlled narrative that Taiwan is doomed to be conquered is welcome, but after observing its rise in recent months, I now believe that the “silicon shield” is a myth — one that is ultimately working against Taiwan. The basic silicon shield idea is that the world, particularly the US, would rush to defend Taiwan against a Chinese invasion because they do not want Beijing to seize the nation’s vital and unique chip industry. However,