US Federal Reserve Governor Ben Bernanke has blamed net inflows of capital from the rest of the world, especially China, for a global saving glut that is driving up the US current account deficit.
Unfortunately, some commentators have echoed this seemingly plausible but outrageously silly idea.
For example, an HSBC economist in Hong Kong, Qu Hongbin (
In all events, the observations cited above reflect a belief that China must lower its domestic saving rate to fuel its economic growth and correct its trade imbalance. Doubtless, part of this argument's credibility lays in China's domestic saving rate of 46 percent of earnings.
But Bernanke and his followers confuse cause and effect in suggesting that an "excess" amount of global savings is the cause of the US' current account deficit, despite low interest rates.
As it is, their macroeconomic analysis is blind to basic economic realities. In the first instance, they are unable to unravel why savers continue to pour money into banks despite ultra-low deposit rates on offer. It turns out that the inflow of funds into banks is the result of monetary pumping by most central banks, which has generated a massive bubble inflated by excessive formation of credit and liquidity.
Bernanke's assertion is also flawed for implying that "excess" savings can damage an economy since "too much" capital can be accumulated. But capital formation is an essential element of economic growth that drives higher living standards.
As such, the implication of his argument is that there is too much growth and people are too well off for their own good. It is a little shocking that such a notion passes intellectual muster.
In all events, the conceptualization offered by Bernanke conveniently ignores the role played by the US Federal Reserve Board in causing the US trade deficit to rise while the dollar has weakened (the current account deficit of the US last year was US$668 billion, or 5.7 percent of GDP, with further rises expected).
In fact, these arguments are redolent of the warmed-over notion of John Maynard Keynes known as the "paradox of thrift." Like Keynes, Bernanke confuses the demand for money (hoarding) with savings and suggest that large cash balances reduce overall demand. But increased savings remain available in the financial system to be lent to investors.
As such, the inflows of foreign funds into the US are not savings, nor can they be fully explained by a strong domestic US capital market. Nor can it be said that the strength of the US economy is pushing up the current account deficit into record territory. If this were the case, the value of the dollar would not have recorded the general weakening trend that was reversed only recently (the US dollar is up by about 7 percent against a basket of major currencies so far this year).
The growing US current account deficit has been driven by ultra-loose monetary policy. America's central bankers have overseen an increase in the money supply (measured as M1) by 27 percent from January 2001 to last December.
As such, the accumulated dollar reserves held by central banks in countries with trade surpluses with the US reflects a type of hoarding that does not reflect increased savings. But these trade surpluses are temporary, since they eventually will be used to purchase imported goods or dollar-based assets like Maytag and Unocal.
The cheap credit policy of the Fed has created an excess supply of dollars domestically and internationally. Low interest rates in the US led to higher spending and nominal incomes, which drove up the demand for imports, causing the trade deficit to balloon. With the dollar pouring relentlessly into foreign exchange markets, the trend has been for it to depreciate against other currencies and many commodities, like oil and gold.
And so it is that this flood of cheap credit, courtesy of US central bankers, has created and kept afloat a gigantic, global Ponzi scheme. Like all pyramid schemes, there is a false sense of shared prosperity. Americans get cheap imports that hold down domestic consumer prices. And foreigners are happy, thinking that they are enjoying export-driven growth while accumulating more dollars, or paper debt mostly denominated in dollars.
Eventually, foreigners will find that their addiction to bits of green money in exchange for their own hard work is doing damage to their economies. Presumably, China will recognize this before it is too late.
But this would require that it abandon the neo-Mercantilist logic that supports the obsession with a "weak" currency to promote exports.
Artificially low interest rates have spawned a global credit bubble that has caused various "imbalances." These include a global housing boom and a trade deficit in the US that is responsible for the massive foreign exchange holdings in economies with trade surpluses. In the case of China, it has also generated an unsustainable and temporary burst of growth in its export-oriented industries. The excess liquidity is also responsible for higher asset prices, especially gold and oil.
History reveals that all "bubbles" either deflate or burst. In either case, an economic slowdown occurs that requires the liquidation of misguided investments that involve unsupported productive capacity.
It is both interesting and troubling to recount the history of Asia's export-led powerhouses. The bursting of Japan's bubble in 1989 ended a long period of high economic growth that was followed by a long period of low growth that continues to this day.
And then East Asia's "miracle" economies hit a wall in 1997 and 1998 that burst their bubbles. It should be rather clear that China is next, so the most pressing question becomes, when?
Christopher Lingle is visiting professor of economics at Universidad Francisco Marroquin in Guatemala.
Monday was the 37th anniversary of former president Chiang Ching-kuo’s (蔣經國) death. Chiang — a son of former president Chiang Kai-shek (蔣介石), who had implemented party-state rule and martial law in Taiwan — has a complicated legacy. Whether one looks at his time in power in a positive or negative light depends very much on who they are, and what their relationship with the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) is. Although toward the end of his life Chiang Ching-kuo lifted martial law and steered Taiwan onto the path of democratization, these changes were forced upon him by internal and external pressures,
Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) caucus whip Fu Kun-chi (傅?萁) has caused havoc with his attempts to overturn the democratic and constitutional order in the legislature. If we look at this devolution from the context of a transition to democracy from authoritarianism in a culturally Chinese sense — that of zhonghua (中華) — then we are playing witness to a servile spirit from a millennia-old form of totalitarianism that is intent on damaging the nation’s hard-won democracy. This servile spirit is ingrained in Chinese culture. About a century ago, Chinese satirist and author Lu Xun (魯迅) saw through the servile nature of
In their New York Times bestseller How Democracies Die, Harvard political scientists Steven Levitsky and Daniel Ziblatt said that democracies today “may die at the hands not of generals but of elected leaders. Many government efforts to subvert democracy are ‘legal,’ in the sense that they are approved by the legislature or accepted by the courts. They may even be portrayed as efforts to improve democracy — making the judiciary more efficient, combating corruption, or cleaning up the electoral process.” Moreover, the two authors observe that those who denounce such legal threats to democracy are often “dismissed as exaggerating or
The National Development Council (NDC) on Wednesday last week launched a six-month “digital nomad visitor visa” program, the Central News Agency (CNA) reported on Monday. The new visa is for foreign nationals from Taiwan’s list of visa-exempt countries who meet financial eligibility criteria and provide proof of work contracts, but it is not clear how it differs from other visitor visas for nationals of those countries, CNA wrote. The NDC last year said that it hoped to attract 100,000 “digital nomads,” according to the report. Interest in working remotely from abroad has significantly increased in recent years following improvements in